Pubdate: Mon, 9 Mar 2009
Source: Winnipeg Free Press (CN MB)
Copyright: 2009 The Economist Newspaper Limited
Contact: http://www.winnipegfreepress.com/info/letters/index.html
Website: http://www.winnipegfreepress.com/
Details: http://www.mapinc.org/media/502
Note: Editorial reprinted from The Economist

END THE DRUG WARS

Legalization Drives Away Gangsters and Makes Health, Not Crime, the Issue

A hundred years ago, a group of foreign diplomats gathered in 
Shanghai for the first-ever international effort to ban trade in a 
narcotic drug. On Feb. 26, 1909, they agreed to set up the 
International Opium Commission -- just a few decades after Britain 
had fought a war with China to assert its right to peddle the stuff.

Many other bans of mood-altering drugs have followed. In 1998, the UN 
General Assembly committed member countries to achieving a "drug-free 
world" and to "or significantly reducing" the production of opium, 
cocaine and cannabis by 2008.

That is the kind of promise politicians love to make. It assuages the 
sense of moral panic that has been the handmaiden of prohibition for 
a century. It is intended to reassure the parents of teenagers across 
the world. Yet it is a hugely irresponsible promise, because it 
cannot be fulfilled.

This week, ministers from around the world gather in Vienna to set 
international drug policy for the next decade. Like First World War 
generals, many will claim that all that is needed is more of the same.

In fact, the war on drugs has been a disaster, creating failed states 
in the developing world even as addiction has flourished in the rich 
world. By any sensible measure, this 100-year struggle has been 
illiberal, murderous and pointless. That is why The Economist 
continues to believe that the least bad policy is to legalize drugs.

"Least bad" does not mean good. Legalization, though clearly better 
for producer countries, would bring (different) risks to consumer 
countries. Many vulnerable drug-takers would suffer. But it is the 
view of The Economist that more would gain.

Nowadays, the UN Office on Drugs and Crime no longer talks about a 
drug-free world. Its boast is that the drug market has "stabilized," 
meaning that more than 200 million people, or almost five per cent of 
the world's adult population, still take illegal drugs -- roughly the 
same proportion as a decade ago. (Like most purported drug facts, 
this one is an educated guess: evidential rigour is another casualty 
of illegality.)

The production of cocaine and opium is probably about the same as it 
was a decade ago; that of cannabis is higher. Consumption of cocaine 
has declined gradually in the United States from its peak in the 
early 1980s, but the path is uneven (it remains higher than in the 
mid-1990s), and it is rising in many places, including Europe.

This is not for want of effort. The United States alone spends some 
$40 billion each year on trying to eliminate the supply of drugs.

It arrests 1.5 million of its citizens each year for drug offences, 
locking up half a million of them; tougher drug laws are the main 
reason why one in five black American men spend some time behind bars.

In the developing world, blood is being shed at an astonishing rate. 
In Mexico, more than 800 policemen and soldiers have been killed 
since December 2006 (and the annual overall death toll is running at 
over 6,000). Last week, yet another leader of a troubled drug-ridden 
country -- Guinea Bissau -- was assassinated.

Yet prohibition itself vitiates the efforts of the drug warriors. The 
price of an illegal substance is determined more by the cost of 
distribution than of production.

Take cocaine: the markup between coca field and consumer is more than 
a hundredfold. Even if dumping weed killer on the crops of peasant 
farmers quadruples the local price of coca leaves, this tends to have 
little impact on the street price, which is set mainly by the risk of 
getting cocaine into Europe or the United States.

Nowadays, the drug warriors claim to seize close to half of all the 
cocaine that is produced. The street price in the U.S. does seem to 
have risen, and the purity seems to have fallen, over the past year. 
But it is not clear that drug demand drops when prices rise.

On the other hand, there is plenty of evidence that the drug business 
quickly adapts to market disruption. At best, effective repression 
merely forces it to shift production sites. Thus, opium has moved 
from Turkey and Thailand to Myanmar and southern Afghanistan, where 
it undermines the West's efforts to defeat the Taliban.

Indeed, far from reducing crime, prohibition has fostered gangsterism 
on a scale that the world has never seen. According to the UN's 
perhaps inflated estimate, the illegal drug industry is worth some 
$320 billion a year.

In the West, it makes criminals of otherwise law-abiding citizens 
(the current American president could easily have ended up in prison 
for his youthful experiments with "blow").

It also makes drugs more dangerous: addicts buy heavily adulterated 
cocaine and heroin; many use dirty needles to inject themselves, 
spreading HIV; the wretches who succumb to "crack" or "meth" are 
outside the law, with only their pushers to "treat" them. But it is 
countries in the emerging world that pay most of the price.

Even a relatively developed democracy such as Mexico now finds itself 
in a life-or-death struggle against gangsters. American officials, 
including a former drug czar, have publicly worried about having a 
"narco state" as their neighbour.

The failure of the drug war has led a few of its braver generals, 
especially from Europe and Latin America, to suggest shifting the 
focus from locking up people to public health and "harm reduction" 
(such as encouraging addicts to use clean needles).

This approach would put more emphasis on public education and the 
treatment of addicts, and less on the harassment of peasants who grow 
coca and the punishment of consumers of "soft" drugs for personal use.

That would be a step in the right direction. But it is unlikely to be 
adequately funded, and it does nothing to take organized crime out of 
the picture.

Legalization would not only drive away the gangsters; it would 
transform drugs from a law-and-order problem into a public-health 
problem, which is how they ought to be treated.

Governments would tax and regulate the drug trade, and use the funds 
raised (and the billions saved on law-enforcement) to educate the 
public about the risks of drug-taking and to treat addiction. The 
sale of drugs to minors should remain banned.

Different drugs would command different levels of taxation and 
regulation. This system would be fiddly and imperfect, requiring 
constant monitoring and hard-to-measure trade-offs.

Post-tax prices should be set at a level that would strike a balance 
between damping down use on the one hand, and discouraging a black 
market and the desperate acts of theft and prostitution to which 
addicts now resort to feed their habits.

Selling even this flawed system to people in producer countries, 
where organized crime is the central political issue, is fairly easy. 
The tough part comes in the consumer countries, where addiction is 
the main political battle.

Plenty of American parents might accept that legalization would be 
the right answer for the people of Latin America, Asia and Africa; 
they might even see its usefulness in the fight against terrorism. 
But their immediate fear would be for their own children.

That fear is based in large part on the presumption that more people 
would take drugs under a legal regime. That presumption may be wrong. 
There is no correlation between the harshness of drug laws and the 
incidence of drug-taking: citizens living under tough regimes 
(notably America but also Britain) take more drugs, not fewer.

Embarrassed drug warriors blame this on alleged cultural differences, 
but even in fairly similar countries tough rules make little 
difference to the number of addicts: harsh Sweden and more liberal 
Norway have precisely the same addiction rates.

Legalization might reduce both supply (pushers by definition push) 
and demand (part of that dangerous thrill would go). Nobody knows for 
certain. But it is hard to argue that sales of any product that is 
made cheaper, safer and more widely available would fall. Any honest 
proponent of legalization would be wise to assume that drug-taking as 
a whole would rise.

There are two main reasons for arguing that prohibition should be 
scrapped all the same. The first is one of liberal principle. 
Although some illegal drugs are extremely dangerous to some people, 
most are not especially harmful. (Tobacco is more addictive than 
virtually all of them.)

Most consumers of illegal drugs, including cocaine and even heroin, 
take them only occasionally. They do so because they derive enjoyment 
from them (as they do from whisky or a Marlboro Light). It is not the 
state's job to stop them from doing so.

What about addiction? That is partly covered by this first argument, 
as the harm involved is primarily visited upon the user. But 
addiction can also inflict misery on the families and especially the 
children of any addict, and involves wider social costs.

That is why discouraging and treating addiction should be the 
priority for drug policy. Hence the second argument: legalization 
offers the opportunity to deal with addiction properly.

By providing honest information about the health risks of different 
drugs, and pricing them accordingly, governments could steer 
consumers towards the least harmful ones.

Prohibition has failed to prevent the proliferation of designer 
drugs, dreamed up in laboratories. Legalization might encourage 
legitimate drug companies to try to improve the stuff that people 
take. The resources gained from tax and saved on repression would 
allow governments to guarantee treatment to addicts -- a way of 
making legalization more politically palatable.

The success of developed countries in stopping people smoking 
tobacco, which is similarly subject to tax and regulation, provides 
grounds for hope.

The Economist first argued for legalization 20 years ago. Reviewing 
the evidence again, prohibition seems even more harmful, especially 
for the poor and weak of the world.

Legalization would not drive gangsters completely out of drugs; as 
with alcohol and cigarettes, there would be taxes to avoid and rules 
to subvert. Nor would it automatically cure failed states like 
Afghanistan. Our solution is a messy one; but a century of manifest 
failure argues for trying it. 
- ---
MAP posted-by: Richard Lake